教育资源为主的文档平台

当前位置: 查字典文档网> 所有文档分类> 高等教育> 法学> an introduction to economic analysis of law

an introduction to economic analysis of law

上传者:唐为义
|
上传时间:2015-04-15
|
次下载

an introduction to economic analysis of law

CHICAGO

JOHN M. OLIN LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER NO. 53

(2D SERIES)

内容需要下载文档才能查看

VALUES AND CONSEQUENCES:

AN INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW

Richard A. Posner

THE LAW SCHOOL

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO

This paper can be downloaded without charge at:

The Chicago Working Paper Series Index:

Values and Consequences:

An Introduction to Economic Analysis of Law

Richard A. Posner1*

I am going to give a very brief, thumbnail sketch of economic analysis of law, and then focus on just two uses of the analysis, and in doing so try to give you a bit of its flavor. The first use is to make law simpler to understand and evaluate; and the second is to press you to defend your values.

That there is a relation between economics and law has been known for an awfully long time, at least since Hobbes’s discussion of property in the seventeenth century. But until very recently, the relation received focused attention only in relation to a handful of legal fields, mainly antitrust and public utility regulation, that dealt explicitly with competition and monopoly, which as early as the 1930s were receiving the sustained and sophisticated attention of leading English and American economists. (Competition and monopoly had received the attention of economists since Adam Smith; hence the qualification “sustained and sophisticated.”)

In retrospect, an economic literature dealing with other fields of law, notably Robert Hale’s work on contract law, which also dates from the 1930s, can be identified. But even after the Journal of Law and Economics commenced publication—at this law school, naturally—in 1958, the “law and economics” movement, if discernible at all, would have been associated primarily with problems of competition and monopoly, although occasional forays had been made into taxation (Henry Simons) and corporations (Henry Manne), even patents (Arnold Plant), and if one went back to the eighteenth century there was Bentham’s largely forgotten utilitarian—essentially, economic—analysis of crime and punishment. It was not until 1961, when Ronald Coase’s article “The Problem of Social Cost” was published,2 and at about the same time Guido Calabresi’s first article on torts,3 that an economic theory of the common law could be glimpsed. When Gary Becker published his article “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,”4 reviving and refining Bentham, it began to seem that perhaps no field of law could not be placed under the lens of economics with illuminating results. And within a few years, sure enough, papers on the economics of contract law, civil and criminal procedure, property, 1* Chief Judge, United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit; Senior Lecturer, University of Chicago Law School. This is the text of a Coase Lecture given at the University of Chicago Law School on January 6, 1998.

2 3 Journal of Law and Economics 1 (1960 [but actually published in 1961]).

3 Guido Calabresi, “Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts,” 70 Yale Law Journal 499 (1961).

4 76 Journal of Political Economy 169 (1968).

1 Values and Consequences

consumer protection, and other areas new to economists had appeared and the rough shape of the mature field was discernible. Later, books and articles would extend the economic analysis of law into such fields as employment, admiralty, intellectual property, family law, legislation, environmental law, administrative law, conflict of laws, and judicial behavior; and this is only a partial list. The field has developed to the point where the dean of the Yale Law School, a critic of the field, said recently: “The law and economics movement was and continues to be an enormous enlivening force in American legal thought and, I would say, today continues and remains the single most influential jurisprudential school in this country.”5

The economic analysis of law, as it now exists not only in the United States but also in Europe, which has its own flourishing law and economics association, has both positive (that is, descriptive) and normative aspects. It tries to explain and predict the behavior of participants in and persons regulated by the law. It also tries to improve law by pointing out respects in which existing or proposed laws have unintended or undesirable consequences, whether on economic efficiency, or the distribution of income and wealth, or other values. It is not merely an ivory-towered enterprise, at least in the United States, where the law and economics movement is understood to have influenced legal reform in a number of important areas. These areas include antitrust, the regulation of public utilities and common carriers, environmental regulation, the computation of damages in personal injury suits, the regulation of the securities markets, the federal sentencing guidelines, the division of property and the calculation of alimony in divorce cases, and the law governing investment by pension funds and other trustees, and to have been a significant factor in the deregulation movement and in free-market ideology generally. Most major and many minor law schools have one or two full-time economists on their faculty; a number of law professors have Ph.D.’s in economics; there are six scholarly journals devoted to economic analysis of law, with a seventh on the way; the use of economists as expert witnesses has become conventional in a range of important fields; judicial opinions refer to economic concepts and cite economic books and articles; and a number of federal judges, including a Justice of the Supreme Court (Stephen Breyer), are alumni of the law and economics movement. Economic analysis of law is generally considered the most significant development in legal thought in the United States since legal realism petered out a half century ago.

Noneconomists often associate economics with money, capitalism, selfishness—with a reductive, unrealistic conception of human motivation and behavior, a formidable mathematical apparatus, and a penchant for cynical, pessimistic, and conservative conclusions. It earned the sobriquet of “the dismal science” because of Thomas Malthus’s thesis that famine, war, and sexual abstinence were the only ways in which population and food supply could be equilibrated. The essence of economics is none of these things, 5 Remarks of Anthony T. Kronman, The Second Driker Forum for Excellence in the Law, 42 Wayne Law Review 115, 160 (1995).

University of Chicago Law School, Program in Law and Economics Working Paper 53 2

however. The essence is extremely simple, although the simplicity is deceptive; the simple can be subtle, can be counterintuitive; its antithesis is “complicated,” not “difficult.”

Most economic analysis consists of tracing out the consequences of assuming that people are more or less rational in their social interactions. In the case of the activities that interest the law, these people may be criminals or prosecutors or parties to accidents or taxpayers or tax collectors or striking workers—or even law students. Students treat grades as prices, so that unless the university administration intervenes, unpopular professors, in order to keep up their enrollments, will sometimes compensate students for the low perceived value of the course by giving them higher grades, that is, by raising the price that the professor pays for the student.

I said that the tracing out of consequences is subtle as well as simple, and here is an example. Have you heard of the spendthrift trust? That is a trust, very common, indeed standard, in which the trustee is forbidden to pay out any of the money or other property in the trust to the creditors of the trust’s beneficiaries. The law will enforce such a restriction, yet it has seemed to many students of the law a fraud on creditors; for the trust beneficiary, assuming that his whole wealth is in the spendthrift trust, can borrow all he wants, spend what he borrows, and not be forced to repay the lenders. But if you think about this for a moment, you’ll be driven to the opposite conclusion—that, provided the provision preventing creditors from reaching into the trust is not concealed, a spendthrift trust limits borrowing by the trust beneficiary, because he can’t offer security to the lender. And the next step in the analysis is to see how increasing the rights of debtors in bankruptcy, far from causing an avalanche of reckless borrowing, could reduce the amount of borrowing, and so the incidence of bankruptcy, by causing lenders to make smaller loans to risky borrowers. So lenders may oppose easy bankruptcy not because they fear there will be more defaults, but because they fear a reduction in the volume of loans. To see this, imagine how many, or rather how few, loans there would be if borrowers had no obligation to repay. Notice also how creditors are as hurt by excessively stringent as by excessively lenient bankruptcy rules: if creditors had the legal right, as under ancient Roman law, to carve up a defaulting borrower into as many pieces as there were creditors, most people would be afraid to borrow. Can you see now why loan sharks in Chicago break the legs of defaulting borrowers, but do not kill them?

Rationality implies decision making, and people often have to make decisions under conditions of profound uncertainty; fortunately, economists have devoted a good deal of attention to decision under uncertainty. A simple but important example of a law-related decision under uncertainty is the decision as to how much care to take to avoid an accident. The accident will occur with probability P, and let us assume that if it does occur it will impose a cost that I’ll call L, for loss; and assume further that eliminating the possibility of such an accident would impose on the potential injurer a cost, which I’ll call B (for burden). Then it is easily seen that the cost of avoiding the accident will be 3 Values and Consequences

less than the expected accident cost (or benefit of avoiding the accident) if B is smaller than L discounted (multiplied) by P, or B<PL, and if this condition is satisfied then the potential injurer can be said to be negligent if he fails to take the precaution. This is the negligence formula of Judge Learned Hand, announced in a judicial opinion in 19476 but not recognized as an economic formula for negligence until many years later. It is a simple formula but its elaboration and application to specific doctrines in the law of torts have generated an immense and illuminating literature.

By glancing at the Hand Formula you can see how an injurer could be deemed negligent even if the probability of an accident were very low (because B might be low or L very high), or even if the cost of avoiding the injury were very high (because P and/or L might be very high). You can put a minus sign before B, and thus model the case in which the injurer would incur a cost saving by not injuring: the case, in short, of deliberate injury; and you would see how in that case the injury is never cost-justified. Or you can think of B not as the cost of taking a precaution, but as the cost of reducing the output or other activity of the potential injurer, since that’s another way of avoiding injuring people. And that will give you a clue to the role, or a role, of strict liability in the law. Suppose you kept a tiger in your backyard for self-defense, and the tiger got out and bit a neighbor’s head off. It would be a case of high P and high L, and maybe high B in the sense that you couldn’t have been more careful than you were to keep the tiger in your yard; but B might have been low if viewed as the cost of not having a tiger at all, but substituting another method of self-protection; and in fact this is a case where strict liability is imposed.

Well, I could go on and on with these examples, moving from one tort doctrine to another through the whole field of torts and then to contracts and property and so on throughout the legal system. But time does not permit that and if you want a fuller sketch of the field today, I suggest you take a look at my book Economic Analysis of Law, a new edition of which has just appeared.7 I want to move on to the two specific uses of economic analysis that I said I’d concentrate on—making law simpler and challenging you to defend your values. I shall begin with a case that the Supreme Court decided in 1911, an antitrust case called Dr. Miles.8 The issue was the legality under the Sherman Act of a contract that a supplier of patent medicines entered into with his dealers forbidding them to charge a price for his medicines lower than the retail price that he fixed; this is the practice known as resale price maintenance. The Supreme Court, holding the practice illegal, noted that it had the same effect as would an agreement among the dealers to fix the price at which they would sell Dr. Miles’s medicines: a dealers’ cartel. But the Court overlooked another effect. If dealers cannot compete in price, yet would 6 United States v. Carroll Towing Co., 159 F.2d 169 (2d Cir. 1947).

7 Richard A. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law (5th ed. 1998).

8 Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911).

University of Chicago Law School, Program in Law and Economics Working Paper 53 4

版权声明:此文档由查字典文档网用户提供,如用于商业用途请与作者联系,查字典文档网保持最终解释权!

下载文档

热门试卷

2016年四川省内江市中考化学试卷
广西钦州市高新区2017届高三11月月考政治试卷
浙江省湖州市2016-2017学年高一上学期期中考试政治试卷
浙江省湖州市2016-2017学年高二上学期期中考试政治试卷
辽宁省铁岭市协作体2017届高三上学期第三次联考政治试卷
广西钦州市钦州港区2016-2017学年高二11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市钦州港区2017届高三11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市钦州港区2016-2017学年高一11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市高新区2016-2017学年高二11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市高新区2016-2017学年高一11月月考政治试卷
山东省滨州市三校2017届第一学期阶段测试初三英语试题
四川省成都七中2017届高三一诊模拟考试文科综合试卷
2017届普通高等学校招生全国统一考试模拟试题(附答案)
重庆市永川中学高2017级上期12月月考语文试题
江西宜春三中2017届高三第一学期第二次月考文科综合试题
内蒙古赤峰二中2017届高三上学期第三次月考英语试题
2017年六年级(上)数学期末考试卷
2017人教版小学英语三年级上期末笔试题
江苏省常州西藏民族中学2016-2017学年九年级思想品德第一学期第二次阶段测试试卷
重庆市九龙坡区七校2016-2017学年上期八年级素质测查(二)语文学科试题卷
江苏省无锡市钱桥中学2016年12月八年级语文阶段性测试卷
江苏省无锡市钱桥中学2016-2017学年七年级英语12月阶段检测试卷
山东省邹城市第八中学2016-2017学年八年级12月物理第4章试题(无答案)
【人教版】河北省2015-2016学年度九年级上期末语文试题卷(附答案)
四川省简阳市阳安中学2016年12月高二月考英语试卷
四川省成都龙泉中学高三上学期2016年12月月考试题文科综合能力测试
安徽省滁州中学2016—2017学年度第一学期12月月考​高三英语试卷
山东省武城县第二中学2016.12高一年级上学期第二次月考历史试题(必修一第四、五单元)
福建省四地六校联考2016-2017学年上学期第三次月考高三化学试卷
甘肃省武威第二十三中学2016—2017学年度八年级第一学期12月月考生物试卷

网友关注视频

19 爱护鸟类_第一课时(二等奖)(桂美版二年级下册)_T3763925
青岛版教材五年级下册第四单元(走进军营——方向与位置)用数对确定位置(一等奖)
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《泊秦淮》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,湖北省
第12章 圆锥曲线_12.7 抛物线的标准方程_第一课时(特等奖)(沪教版高二下册)_T274713
19 爱护鸟类_第一课时(二等奖)(桂美版二年级下册)_T502436
化学九年级下册全册同步 人教版 第18集 常见的酸和碱(二)
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《逢入京使》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,安徽省
沪教版牛津小学英语(深圳用) 四年级下册 Unit 2
冀教版英语五年级下册第二课课程解读
30.3 由不共线三点的坐标确定二次函数_第一课时(市一等奖)(冀教版九年级下册)_T144342
二次函数求实际问题中的最值_第一课时(特等奖)(冀教版九年级下册)_T144339
二年级下册数学第三课 搭一搭⚖⚖
沪教版牛津小学英语(深圳用) 四年级下册 Unit 4
苏科版数学八年级下册9.2《中心对称和中心对称图形》
《空中课堂》二年级下册 数学第一单元第1课时
冀教版小学数学二年级下册第二周第2课时《我们的测量》宝丰街小学庞志荣.mp4
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《老山界》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,安徽省
小学英语单词
外研版英语七年级下册module3 unit1第二课时
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《老山界》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,安徽省
冀教版小学数学二年级下册第二单元《有余数除法的整理与复习》
精品·同步课程 历史 八年级 上册 第15集 近代科学技术与思想文化
冀教版小学数学二年级下册第二单元《余数和除数的关系》
二年级下册数学第二课
北师大版八年级物理下册 第六章 常见的光学仪器(二)探究凸透镜成像的规律
外研版八年级英语下学期 Module3
北师大版小学数学四年级下册第15课小数乘小数一
北师大版数学 四年级下册 第三单元 第二节 小数点搬家
8 随形想象_第一课时(二等奖)(沪教版二年级上册)_T3786594
第五单元 民族艺术的瑰宝_16. 形形色色的民族乐器_第一课时(岭南版六年级上册)_T3751175