教育资源为主的文档平台

当前位置: 查字典文档网> 所有文档分类> 高等教育> 经济学> SSRN-id1407747

SSRN-id1407747

上传者:戴学东
|
上传时间:2015-05-04
|
次下载

SSRN-id1407747

经济学之反垄断(英文文献)

Horizontal Mergers, Collusion, and Stockholder Wealth

B. Espen Eckbo?

University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Y8, Canada

November 1981

Forthcoming in the Journal of Financial Economics

JEL classifications: G34, G38, L12, L41 Keywords: Merger, collusion, market power, antitrust, efficiency, rivals, industry rents

Abstract

This paper tests the hypothesis that horizontal mergers generate positive abnormal returns to

stockholders of the bidder and target firms because they increase the probability of successful

collusion among rival producers. Under the collusion hypothesis, rivals of the merging firms

benefit from the merger since successful collusion limits output and raises product prices and/or

lowers factor prices. This proposition is tested on a large sample of horizontal mergers in

mining and manufacturing industries, including mergers challenged by the government with

violating antitrust laws, and a ―control‖ sample of vertical mergers taking place in the same

industries. While we find that the antitrust law enforcement agencies systematically select

relatively profitable mergers for prosecution, there is little evidence indicating that the mergers

would have had collusive, anticompetitive effects.

This paper, which is based on my University of Rochester dissertation, has benefitted greatly from the ―visible hands‖ of my thesis committee: Gregg A. Jarrell, Michael C. Jensen and G. William Schwert. I have also received helpful comments from Fisher Black, Claudio Loderer, Avner Kalay, Wayne Mikkelson, Rex Thompson, Jerry Warner, the participants of the finance and industrial economics workshops at New York University, University of British Columbia, and University of Chicago, and the referee, Eugene Fama. The financial support of the Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, and the Center for Research in Government Policy and Business at the University of Rochester, is gratefully acknowledged. Electronic copy available at: http://wendang.chazidian.com/abstract=1407747

经济学之反垄断(英文文献)

1 Introduction

The merger literature contains a substantial amount of evidence indicating that stockholders of merging firms earn positive abnormal returns from merger activity.1 A standard interpretation of this evidence is that control over the target firms resources enables the successful bidder to initiate a revaluation of its own (as well as the targets) shares by implementing a higher-valued operating strategy. Following this view, the stockholder gains reflect an increase in the expected spread between the merging firms future revenues and costs. However, the more difficult issue of whether the gains predominantly originate in cost-side effects (―productive efficiency‖ theories) or in revenue-side effects (―market power‖ theories) has remained unanswered. Indeed, despite the widespread public concern with allegedly anti-competitive consequences of mergers, reliable evidence on the importance of market power theories in the context of this particular corporate activity is almost non-existent.

This paper examines a necessary condition for the proposition that horizontal mergers have collusive, anticompetitive effects. In our context, the central characteristic of the collusion theory is its implication for mergerinduced changes in relative product (and factor) prices. However, noting that changes in product prices induce changes in the market value of firms trading at these prices, we instead focus on the abnormal stock returns to the merging firms and their horizontal rivals. There are several reasons why this focus is of particular interest. For example, the potential social welfare loss from post-merger collusion on price can be entirely offset by an increase in competition on non-price variables, such as product quality and service. While product prices are not necessarily sensitive to changes in non-price competition, under the efficient markets/rational expectations hypothesis stock prices reflect the combined effect of all changes in the firms expected future cash flows. At a minimum, it is this combined effect which should govern a decision to challenge the merger under antitrust laws. Furthermore, while it is difficult to obtain a precise estimate of the time of the mergers impact on product prices, it is well established that stock prices react quickly to public merger announcements. Moreover, while there exists no generally acceptable theory generating ―normal‖ or expected values of product prices, the finance literature provides a model for equilibrium expected stock returns. Finally, the availability of stock price data A brief discussion of some of this evidence, and how it relates to the findings of this paper, is given in Section 4.

1

Electronic copy available at: http://wendang.chazidian.com/abstract=1407747

经济学之反垄断(英文文献)

encourages the use of sample sizes which would be infeasible if we were to rely on product prices, or other firm or industry specific characteristics.

With a sample of 259 horizontal and vertical mergers in mining and manufacturing industries, of which 76 were challenged by the government under claims they ―monopolized‖ product markets, we find that the collusion hypothesis is generally rejected by the data. Rather, the evidence is consistent with the proposition that antitrust policy over the past two decades in part has protected relatively high-cost from relatively low-cost producers by restricting the opportunity to implement lower-cost production techniques by means of merger. This conclusion, which is also to some extent supported by Stillman (1983), casts serious doubt on the validity of a ―consumer protection‖ rationale for this form of government intervention in the market for corporate control.

The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses the testable implications of the collusion hypothesis. Section 3 describes the procedure used to select the merger sample and the portfolio of horizontal rivals for each merger. Section 4 contains the empirical results, and relates the evidence to the findings of previous work. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2 Testable implications of the collusion hypothesis

Merger-related anticipated changes in product or factor prices translate into merger-related abnor- mal performance by the direct competitors of the bidder and target firms. Below, the implications of the collusion hypothesis are stated in terms of this abnormal performance in response to two consecutive public announcements, each significantly changing the probability that the merger will take place. The first is the merger proposal announcement, the second is the announcement that a ―Section 7‖ complaint against the merger has been (or will be) filed by the Federal Trade Commission or the Antitrust Division of the Justice Department.2

2.1 Implications for the performance of the rivals

The traditional collusion argument presumes the incentive to coordinate the production rates of the individual rivals within an industry is a function of the costs of monitoring the collusive agreement. Section 7 of the Clayton Act prohibits one corporation from acquiring the stock or assets of another ―if the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly‘. The merger proposal and the antitrust complaint announcement dates are taken from the Wall Street Journal. In the remainder of the paper, the phrase ―antitrust challenge‘ refers to the antitrust complaint. 2

2

经济学之反垄断(英文文献)

Using Stigler (1964) theory of oligopoly, a horizontal merger can reduce the monitoring costs by reducing the number of independent producers in the industry. The fewer the members of the industry the more ―visible‖ are each producers actions, and the higher is the probability of detecting members who try to cheat on the cartel by increasing output. The higher this probability, the lower the expected gains from cheating, and the more stable (and profitable) is the cartel in the short run.3

Since effective collusion generates monopoly (or monopsony) rents, the collusion hypothesis

implies that the horizontal rivals of the merging firms should earn positive abnormal returns around the merger proposal announcement. The same conclusion holds for rivals expected to remain outside the collusive agreement, in particular since these firms will not bear the costs of restricting output (they are ―free-riding‖ on the higher product price). Conversely, the rivals should earn negative abnormal returns in response to the news of a subsequent antitrust complaint, provided the complaint is expected to significantly increase the costs of collusion (for example, by prohibiting the merger from taking place). Such a complaint announcement will reverse the expectations of increased monopoly (monopsony) rents caused by the earlier merger proposal.

2.2 Productive efficiency and implications for regulation

The above implications of the collusion hypothesis are necessary but not sufficient to conclude a given merger is truly anticompetitive. As indicated in Table 1, a pattern of abnormal returns to the merging firms and their rivals which is consistent with collusion can also be consistent with productive efficiency. The latter hypothesis represents a class of theories predicting an increase in the market value of the merging firms due to the implementation of a more cost-efficient produc- tion/investment policy after the merger is consummated.4 In general, the efficiency hypothesis does not restrict the sign of the abnormal returns to the rivals. To see why, note that with productive Of course, in the absence of government supported entry barriers (such as patents, licences, tariffs, etc.), the collusion argument assumes the degree of resource specialization in the industry is sufficient to slow down the entry process. See, for example, Stigler (1950) for a discussion of the minimum necessary conditions for merger-for- monopoly (or oligopoly) to take place. Note also that the collusion hypothesis does not necessarily presume a complete cartelization of the industry. A subset of firms may find it optimal to form a cartel agreement after the merger has been completed and produce a marginal output (or input) restriction on their own, a scenario which is analytically equivalent to the classical ―dominant firm‖ or ―price umbrella‖ model. 4The productive efficiency hypothesis covers a wide range of possible specific reasons for merger, among others, realization of technological complementarities, replacement of inefficient management teams, utilization of unused corporate tax credits, and avoiding bankruptcy costs. A general review of traditional non-monopolistic hypotheses of merger motivation can be found in Steiner (1975). 3

3

经济学之反垄断(英文文献)

efficiency each of the two merger-related announcements can have a product/factor price effect and a possibly offsetting information effect. That is, the intensified competition in product and factor markets (the merging firms are being replaced by a more competitive corporate entity) tends to result in lower product prices and higher factor prices. This price effect causes a negative change in the market value of the rivals at the time of the proposal announcement, and a positive (reversed) effect at the time of the antitrust complaint. On the other hand, since the production technologies of close competitors are (by definition) closely related, the news of a proposed efficient merger can also signal opportunities for the rivals to increase their productivity.5 Similarly, the news of the an- titrust complaint can signal a significant restriction in the future merger opportunities of the rivals (cf. ―landmark‖ cases). For each of the two announcements the total wealth impact on the rivals is the sum of the product/factor price effect and the (possibly offsetting) information effect, leaving no necessary restriction on the sign of the rivals abnormal returns under the efficiency hypothesis6

For the purpose of drawing normative conclusions concerning merger regulation, a further limi- tation of the tests should be emphasized. The collusion and efficiency hypotheses are not mutually exclusive, which means the observed security value changes resulting from a given merger can rep- resent the sum of simultaneous positive and negative effects due to collusion and efficiency. In principle, the dollar value of the efficiency gains realized within the merging firms can outweigh the negative social welfare effects of collusion. Therefore, even a pattern of abnormal returns to the rivals which is truly consistent with the collusion hypothesis is not sufficient evidence to conclude that public regulation of the merger will increase social welfare. On the other hand, and this con- stitutes the basic motivation of the paper, evidence which according to Table 1 is inconsistent with collusion, but consistent with value-maximizing behavior on the part of the merging firms, implies that blocking the merger will reduce social welfare. Essentially, such evidence would indicate that For example, the proposal announcement may disseminate information which enables the rivals to imitate the technological innovation motivating the acquisition. If such innovation activity requires merger, then the stock prices of the rivals will be bid up in anticipation of the expected gains from the future merger activity. Interestingly, Jarrell and Bradley (1980) presents evidence consistent with the proposition that the introduction of public disclosure laws has resulted in extensive dissemination of technological information associated with tender offers, thereby significantly reducing the private gains from company takeovers. Note also that if the technological innovation is scale increasing, then imitation by the rivals will further reduce the product price (and increase prices of specialized inputs). In fact, merger waves may be a race by imitators to lower their costs in response to this continuing price decrease. 6In principle, one could discriminate between the collusion and efficiency theories by examining the abnormal returns to the merging firms corporate customers and suppliers of inputs. For example, relative to the proposal announcement, corporate customers and suppliers should lose under the collusion hypothesis and gain under the efficiency hypothesis. However, tests based on this notion are difficult since it is necessary to identify customers and suppliers who cannot switch their purchases/sales to other industries at a low cost. 4

版权声明:此文档由查字典文档网用户提供,如用于商业用途请与作者联系,查字典文档网保持最终解释权!

下载文档

热门试卷

2016年四川省内江市中考化学试卷
广西钦州市高新区2017届高三11月月考政治试卷
浙江省湖州市2016-2017学年高一上学期期中考试政治试卷
浙江省湖州市2016-2017学年高二上学期期中考试政治试卷
辽宁省铁岭市协作体2017届高三上学期第三次联考政治试卷
广西钦州市钦州港区2016-2017学年高二11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市钦州港区2017届高三11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市钦州港区2016-2017学年高一11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市高新区2016-2017学年高二11月月考政治试卷
广西钦州市高新区2016-2017学年高一11月月考政治试卷
山东省滨州市三校2017届第一学期阶段测试初三英语试题
四川省成都七中2017届高三一诊模拟考试文科综合试卷
2017届普通高等学校招生全国统一考试模拟试题(附答案)
重庆市永川中学高2017级上期12月月考语文试题
江西宜春三中2017届高三第一学期第二次月考文科综合试题
内蒙古赤峰二中2017届高三上学期第三次月考英语试题
2017年六年级(上)数学期末考试卷
2017人教版小学英语三年级上期末笔试题
江苏省常州西藏民族中学2016-2017学年九年级思想品德第一学期第二次阶段测试试卷
重庆市九龙坡区七校2016-2017学年上期八年级素质测查(二)语文学科试题卷
江苏省无锡市钱桥中学2016年12月八年级语文阶段性测试卷
江苏省无锡市钱桥中学2016-2017学年七年级英语12月阶段检测试卷
山东省邹城市第八中学2016-2017学年八年级12月物理第4章试题(无答案)
【人教版】河北省2015-2016学年度九年级上期末语文试题卷(附答案)
四川省简阳市阳安中学2016年12月高二月考英语试卷
四川省成都龙泉中学高三上学期2016年12月月考试题文科综合能力测试
安徽省滁州中学2016—2017学年度第一学期12月月考​高三英语试卷
山东省武城县第二中学2016.12高一年级上学期第二次月考历史试题(必修一第四、五单元)
福建省四地六校联考2016-2017学年上学期第三次月考高三化学试卷
甘肃省武威第二十三中学2016—2017学年度八年级第一学期12月月考生物试卷

网友关注

[整理版]2013年度仲恺农业工程学院国家奖学金请求审批表填写注意事项
agw uidigi简明教程
福建南纺2013年报企业排名及薪酬报告(纺织服装皮革业总资产增长率)福建南纺股份有限公司_九舍会智库
《现代物流基础》供应链管理中的供应链合作伙伴的选择(三)
[机械/仪表]中国汽车燃料经济性标准法规及政策研究
2GHz TD-SCDMA Uu接口技术要求part 2-物理层技术规范-2:物理信道和传输信道到物理信道映射_rev1
努力践行科学发展观推动现代渔业又好又快发展——农业部副部长牛盾在2008现代渔业发展暨渔业改革开放三十年论坛上的讲话(摘要)
ppt精品模板-商务3d君子素材合集[新版]
《电工电子技术简明教程》第6章习题
灯塔市渔业可持续发展评价指标体系的构建及评价 construction, evaluation and research on indicator methods fishery sustainable development in dengta city
论中国城市政府在会展业发展中的作用——基于上海市会展业发展现状的分析论文
广博股份2013年报企业排名及薪酬报告(木材造纸印刷业资产负债率)广博集团股份有限公司_九舍会智库
热处理对青椒贮藏生理的影响 Effect of Heat Treatment on the Physiology of Green Pepper During Storage
室内检测合格 仍要坚持通风提防污染
中银绒业2013年报企业排名及薪酬报告(纺织服装皮革业盈利能力)宁夏中银绒业股份有限公司_九舍会智库
法规·体制·环境·机制-建筑工程招标投标中存在问题成因分析
家庭装修招标文件(有能力的单位可以投标或将要装修的朋友可以借鉴)
2010年1-10月份渔业安全生产及水产品质量安全工作自查报告
中国书院大会邀请函
软件工程项目汇报ppt模板
园林工程施工组织与管理学生工作页评价页2013.4.12(1)
2011-2015年中国白色家电行业深度调研及投资前景预测报告(更新版)
中国书院计划暨国学教育工程战略合作纲要
加强渔业环境保护促进渔业可持续发展——玉山县水产养殖病害状况分析及对策
影响居住建筑节能设计因素的分析与的研究——青岛居住建筑节能设计初探论文
新时期最新流动人口管理工作标准规范与管理规章制度及国家强制性条文实施手册
做空间必用的素材
蓝色清新城市剪影ppt模板
联想 官方 lenovo c3 c4 c5系列电脑使用说明书 (win8 c340 c345 c440 c445 c540 c355 c455)
用心服务,筑梦产业发展——2013年工作总结及2014年工作要点

网友关注视频

沪教版牛津小学英语(深圳用) 五年级下册 Unit 12
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《老山界》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,安徽省
沪教版牛津小学英语(深圳用) 四年级下册 Unit 7
第五单元 民族艺术的瑰宝_16. 形形色色的民族乐器_第一课时(岭南版六年级上册)_T1406126
七年级下册外研版英语M8U2reading
外研版英语三起5年级下册(14版)Module3 Unit1
冀教版小学数学二年级下册第二单元《有余数除法的简单应用》
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《泊秦淮》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,湖北省
北师大版八年级物理下册 第六章 常见的光学仪器(二)探究凸透镜成像的规律
第8课 对称剪纸_第一课时(二等奖)(沪书画版二年级上册)_T3784187
二年级下册数学第二课
沪教版八年级下册数学练习册21.4(1)无理方程P18
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《老山界》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,安徽省
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《逢入京使》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,安徽省
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《泊秦淮》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,广东省
外研版英语七年级下册module3 unit2第一课时
8.对剪花样_第一课时(二等奖)(冀美版二年级上册)_T515402
小学英语单词
北师大版数学 四年级下册 第三单元 第二节 小数点搬家
【部编】人教版语文七年级下册《泊秦淮》优质课教学视频+PPT课件+教案,天津市
青岛版教材五年级下册第四单元(走进军营——方向与位置)用数对确定位置(一等奖)
冀教版小学英语五年级下册lesson2教学视频(2)
外研版英语七年级下册module3 unit2第二课时
冀教版小学数学二年级下册第二单元《余数和除数的关系》
沪教版牛津小学英语(深圳用) 五年级下册 Unit 10
外研版英语七年级下册module1unit3名词性物主代词讲解
苏科版数学七年级下册7.2《探索平行线的性质》
第4章 幂函数、指数函数和对数函数(下)_六 指数方程和对数方程_4.7 简单的指数方程_第一课时(沪教版高一下册)_T1566237
冀教版小学数学二年级下册第二周第2课时《我们的测量》宝丰街小学庞志荣.mp4
沪教版八年级下册数学练习册20.4(2)一次函数的应用2P8